Thursday, April 30, 2015

Does Revenue Sharing Affect Competitive Balance in Baseball?

From 1996-2000 the New York Yankees won four out of five World Series; in 2000 their payroll was $92.5 million, more than five times as high as the Minnesota Twins’ $16.5. In that time frame, none of the teams in the bottom half of payroll spending won a single postseason game.[1] But in 2002 and 2003 the Oakland A’s, one of the lowest-spending teams in baseball, made the playoffs both years, at one point winning twenty straight games in a row. What had changed?
In 2002, responding to the lack of competitiveness of small-market teams, Major League Baseball instituted revenue-sharing.  Under that system every team contributed 31% of their revenue to a common pot, with the money redistributed to every team; as well, central funds from national broadcasts were redistributed. At the same time a luxury tax was instituted, fining teams that exceeded a certain threshold of spending. While revenue-sharing was phased in, another trend was taking baseball by storm: sabermetric analysis, more popularly known as moneyball. This approach, popularized by Billy Beane, the General Manager of the Oakland A’s, allowed small-market teams to compete with their richer big-market brothers. While the success of the A’s was certainly impressive, the question remained: had the competitive balance really been restored? Just how much had revenue sharing and moneyball changed baseball? Post-2002, did small-market teams become more competitive because of revenue sharing, and did the cost of a win go down because of the moneyball effect?
To analyze this I am using a time-series cross-sectional analysis for the years 1985-2014. The dependent variable is winning percentage (wins divided by total games). The independent variable is salary share (team payroll divided by league payroll) which controls for the league-wide increases in payroll over the thirty-year period as well as inflation. A dummy variable was created to differentiate between the pre-2002 and post-2002 periods.
Figure 1 below shows the distribution of salary share. It is relatively rare for a team to command more than 6% of the total salary of the league, and only three times has the share been greater than 8% (the Yankees from 2004-2006).





In figure 2 below the relationship is visualized by year, with 2002 indicated as the year that revenue sharing went into effect.



Somewhat counterintuitively, it would appear that revenue sharing had little effect on the distribution of salary share by year. In fact, the opposite would appear to be true. The spread becomes greater after revenue sharing, with the Yankees hitting three of their highest years of salary share after revenue sharing went into effect. This can be explained by the inauguration of the Yankees’ YES television network, which launched in 2002 and is now valued around $3.4 billion, providing the Yankees with a great deal more money to expand payroll.[2]
The effects of revenue-sharing and moneyball post-2002 are shown in Table 1 below:
  

Table 1. Salary and Win-Loss


Win Percentage
(1)
Share of Salary
0.02***

(7.26)

Post-2002
0.00
(0.33)


Constant
0.43***

(42.85)
R-Squared
0.130
Observations
858
t statistics in parentheses. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001


The above model indicates that share of salary as a percentage of the league salary is correlated with win percentage, which should come as no surprise. A 1 unit increase in salary share corresponds to a .02 unit increase in team win percentage. To give an example, in the year 1985 the total league salary was $262 million; that means that spending an extra $2.6 million (about the difference between Baltimore and the Yankees that year) correlated to 3.24 extra wins on average. In that year three out of the four divisions in baseball were won by less than three games, meaning those 3.24 extra wins are quite valuable (whether they were worth $2.6 million is for a GM to decide). By 2014, with a total league salary of $3.19 billion, those same 3.24 wins would cost $31.9 million, or about the price of Alex Rodriguez.
The model also indicates that there is no significant difference between the periods before and after 2002. The interaction effect was negligibly small and not significant at all. This indicates that revenue sharing and moneyball did little to impact the lack of competitive balance in baseball. The effect of moneyball was short-lived, since other teams (especially big-market ones) quickly adopted sabermetrics and thus reduced the edge for small-market teams like Oakland.
One major issue with the findings is the above-mentioned phenomenon of regional sports networks like the Yankee’s YES network. This was an extra revenue stream that was instituted exactly concurrent with revenue sharing, making it difficult to assess the impact of revenue sharing. Nonetheless, the findings show clearly that salary is correlated with win percentage. Neither the effect of moneyball, nor of the revenue sharing, was enough to significantly change that relationship. These findings support the notion that salary caps (like those employed in basketball and football) create more parity and a less direct relationship between money and wins. That is bad for fans of the Yankees, but good for everyone else.









Appendix:
Table 1. Summary Statistics






Mean
Std. Dev.
Min.
Max.
Win Percentage
0.50
0.07
0.27
0.72
Salary Share (%)
3.49
1.26
0.32
9.52
N
858






Do File:
* Preamble
                set more off
                ssc install estout
                cd "G:\"

**merge databases
collapse (sum) salary, by (yearid teamid)
import delimited C:\Users\ad9538a\Desktop\Teams.csv, clear
keep yearid teamid franchid w l era g r
drop if year <=1984
merge 1:1 yearid teamid using G:\Stata\Blogpost_2\Salaries_collapsed.dta

** generate variables
gen winprct = w/g
gen runspergame = r/g
egen totalsalary = sum(salary), by (yearid)
gen salary_share = (salary/totalsalary) * 100
gen salarymil = (salary/1000000)


**transform
gen dummyyear =.
replace dummyyear = 0 if year < 2002
replace dummyyear = 1 if year >= 2002


** time-series reg
encode franchid, gen (team)

sort team yearid

xtset yearid team


** year v. salary graph & histogram
histogram salary_share, frequency ///
                title("Figure 1. Salary Share Histogram", size(large) color(black)) //
               

twoway (scatter salary_share year, xline(2002)), ///
                title("Figure 2. Salary Share by Year", size(large) color(black)) ///
                note("Red line indicates revenue sharing") legend(off) //
                xtitle("year")///
                ytitle("Salary Share (%)") //
               


** win percentage vs. percentage of total salary of the league
xtreg winprct salary_share if year<2002
xtreg winprct salary_share if year>=2002

xtreg winprct salary_share i.dummyyear c.salary_share#dummyyear



*** Summary Statistics
estpost sum winprct salary_share, listwise
                esttab using sum2.rtf, cells("mean(fmt(2)) sd(fmt(2)) min(fmt(2)) max(fmt(2))") ///
                title("Table 1. Summary Statistics") nonumber replace
               
***** Pretty Table
eststo clear
                                eststo: quietly reg winprct salary_share i.dummyyear c.salary_share#dummyyear //
                               
                                esttab using file_nam3.rtf, replace label ///
                                                stats(r2 N, fmt(3 0) labels("R-Squared" "Observations")) ///
                                                legend varlabels(_cons Constant) ///
                                                b(2) t(2) ///
                                                title({\b Table 2. Salary and Win-Loss})
                eststo clear


[1] Levin, Richard; Mitchell, George; Volcker, Paul; Will, George. “The Report of the Independent Members of the Commissioner’s Blue Ribbon Panel on Baseball Economics”. (July 2000). http://www.mlb.com/mlb/downloads/blue_ribbon.pdf

No comments:

Post a Comment